International Financial Management 6e Chapter 7 Solutions
Chapter 7: Market Entry Strategies
Chapter Objectives
Structure Of The Chapter
Entry strategies
Special features of commodity trade
Chapter Summary
Key Terms
Review Questions
Review Question Answers
References
Bibliography
When an organisation has made a decision to enter an overseas market, there are a variety of options open to it. These options vary with cost, risk and the degree of control which can be exercised over them. The simplest form of entry strategy is exporting using either a direct or indirect method such as an agent, in the case of the former, or countertrade, in the case of the latter. More complex forms include truly global operations which may involve joint ventures, or export processing zones. Having decided on the form of export strategy, decisions have to be made on the specific channels. Many agricultural products of a raw or commodity nature use agents, distributors or involve Government, whereas processed materials, whilst not excluding these, rely more heavily on more sophisticated forms of access. These will be expanded on later.
Chapter Objectives
The objectives of the chapter are:
Structure Of The Chapter
The chapter begins by looking at the concept of market entry strategies within the control of a chosen marketing mix. It then goes on to describe the different forms of entry strategy, both direct and indirect exporting and foreign production, and the advantages and disadvantages connected with each method. The chapter gives specific details on "countertrade", which is very prevalent in global marketing, and then concludes by looking at the special features of commodity trading with its "close coupling" between production and marketing.
Basic issues
An organisation wishing to "go international" faces three major issues:
i) Marketing - which countries, which segments, how to manage and implement marketing effort, how to enter - with intermediaries or directly, with what information?ii) Sourcing - whether to obtain products, make or buy?
iii) Investment and control - joint venture, global partner, acquisition?
Decisions in the marketing area focus on the value chain (see figure 7.1). The strategy or entry alternatives must ensure that the necessary value chain activities are performed and integrated.
Figure 7.1 The value chain -marketing function detail
In making international marketing decisions on the marketing mix more attention to detail is required than in domestic marketing. Table 7.1 lists the detail required1.
Table 7.1 Examples of elements included in the export marketing mix
1. Product support |
2. Price support |
3. Promotion/selling support |
4. Inventory support |
5. Distribution support |
6. Service support |
7. Financial support |
Details on the sourcing element have already been covered in the chapter on competitive analysis and strategy. Concerning investment and control, the question really is how far the company wishes to control its own fate. The degree of risk involved, attitudes and the ability to achieve objectives in the target markets are important facets in the decision on whether to license, joint venture or get involved in direct investment.
Cunningham1 (1986) identified five strategies used by firms for entry into new foreign markets:
i) Technical innovation strategy - perceived and demonstrable superior products
ii) Product adaptation strategy - modifications to existing products
iii) Availability and security strategy - overcome transport risks by countering perceived risks
iv) Low price strategy - penetration price and,
v) Total adaptation and conformity strategy - foreign producer gives a straight copy.
In marketing products from less developed countries to developed countries point iii) poses major problems. Buyers in the interested foreign country are usually very careful as they perceive transport, currency, quality and quantity problems. This is true, say, in the export of cotton and other commodities.
Because, in most agricultural commodities, production and marketing are interlinked, the infrastructure, information and other resources required for building market entry can be enormous. Sometimes this is way beyond the scope of private organisations, so Government may get involved. It may get involved not just to support a specific commodity, but also to help the "public good". Whilst the building of a new road may assist the speedy and expeditious transport of vegetables, for example, and thus aid in their marketing, the road can be put to other uses, in the drive for public good utilities. Moreover, entry strategies are often marked by "lumpy investments". Huge investments may have to be undertaken, with the investor paying a high risk price, long before the full utilisation of the investment comes. Good examples of this include the building of port facilities or food processing or freezing facilities. Moreover, the equipment may not be able to be used for other processes, so the asset specific equipment, locked into a specific use, may make the owner very vulnerable to the bargaining power of raw material suppliers and product buyers who process alternative production or trading options. Zimfreeze, Zimbabwe is experiencing such problems. It built a large freezing plant for vegetables but found itself without a contract. It has been forced, at the moment, to accept sub optional volume product materials just in order to keep the plant ticking over.
In building a market entry strategy, time is a crucial factor. The building of an intelligence system and creating an image through promotion takes time, effort and money. Brand names do not appear overnight. Large investments in promotion campaigns are needed. Transaction costs also are a critical factor in building up a market entry strategy and can become a high barrier to international trade. Costs include search and bargaining costs. Physical distance, language barriers, logistics costs and risk limit the direct monitoring of trade partners. Enforcement of contracts may be costly and weak legal integration between countries makes things difficult. Also, these factors are important when considering a market entry strategy. In fact these factors may be so costly and risky that Governments, rather than private individuals, often get involved in commodity systems. This can be seen in the case of the Citrus Marketing Board of Israel. With a monopoly export marketing board, the entire system can behave like a single firm, regulating the mix and quality of products going to different markets and negotiating with transporters and buyers. Whilst these Boards can experience economies of scale and absorb many of the risks listed above, they can shield producers from information about, and from. buyers. They can also become the "fiefdoms" of vested interests and become political in nature. They then result in giving reduced production incentives and cease to be demand or market orientated, which is detrimental to producers.
Normal ways of expanding the markets are by expansion of product line, geographical development or both. It is important to note that the more the product line and/or the geographic area is expanded the greater will be the managerial complexity. New market opportunities may be made available by expansion but the risks may outweigh the advantages, in fact it may be better to concentrate on a few geographic areas and do things well. This is typical of the horticultural industry of Kenya and Zimbabwe. Traditionally these have concentrated on European markets where the markets are well known. Ways to concentrate include concentrating on geographic areas, reducing operational variety (more standard products) or making the organisational form more appropriate. In the latter the attempt is made to "globalise" the offering and the organisation to match it. This is true of organisations like Coca Cola and MacDonald's. Global strategies include "country centred" strategies (highly decentralised and limited international coordination), "local market approaches" (the marketing mix developed with the specific local (foreign) market in mind) or the "lead market approach" (develop a market which will be a best predictor of other markets). Global approaches give economies of scale and the sharing of costs and risks between markets.
Entry strategies
There are a variety of ways in which organisations can enter foreign markets. The three main ways are by direct or indirect export or production in a foreign country (see figure 7.2).
Exporting
Exporting is the most traditional and well established form of operating in foreign markets. Exporting can be defined as the marketing of goods produced in one country into another. Whilst no direct manufacturing is required in an overseas country, significant investments in marketing are required. The tendency may be not to obtain as much detailed marketing information as compared to manufacturing in marketing country; however, this does not negate the need for a detailed marketing strategy.
Figure 7.2 Methods of foreign market entry
The advantages of exporting are:
· manufacturing is home based thus, it is less risky than overseas based
· gives an opportunity to "learn" overseas markets before investing in bricks and mortar
· reduces the potential risks of operating overseas.
The disadvantage is mainly that one can be at the "mercy" of overseas agents and so the lack of control has to be weighed against the advantages. For example, in the exporting of African horticultural products, the agents and Dutch flower auctions are in a position to dictate to producers.
A distinction has to be drawn between passive and aggressive exporting. A passive exporter awaits orders or comes across them by chance; an aggressive exporter develops marketing strategies which provide a broad and clear picture of what the firm intends to do in the foreign market. Pavord and Bogart2 (1975) found significant differences with regard to the severity of exporting problems in motivating pressures between seekers and non-seekers of export opportunities. They distinguished between firms whose marketing efforts were characterized by no activity, minor activity and aggressive activity.
Those firms who are aggressive have clearly defined plans and strategy, including product, price, promotion, distribution and research elements. Passiveness versus aggressiveness depends on the motivation to export. In countries like Tanzania and Zambia, which have embarked on structural adjustment programmes, organisations are being encouraged to export, motivated by foreign exchange earnings potential, saturated domestic markets, growth and expansion objectives, and the need to repay debts incurred by the borrowings to finance the programmes. The type of export response is dependent on how the pressures are perceived by the decision maker. Piercy (1982)3 highlights the fact that the degree of involvement in foreign operations depends on "endogenous versus exogenous" motivating factors, that is, whether the motivations were as a result of active or aggressive behaviour based on the firm's internal situation (endogenous) or as a result of reactive environmental changes (exogenous).
If the firm achieves initial success at exporting quickly all to the good, but the risks of failure in the early stages are high. The "learning effect" in exporting is usually very quick. The key is to learn how to minimise risks associated with the initial stages of market entry and commitment - this process of incremental involvement is called "creeping commitment" (see figure 7.3).
Figure 7.3 Aggressive and passive export paths
Exporting methods include direct or indirect export. In direct exporting the organisation may use an agent, distributor, or overseas subsidiary, or act via a Government agency. In effect, the Grain Marketing Board in Zimbabwe, being commercialised but still having Government control, is a Government agency. The Government, via the Board, are the only permitted maize exporters. Bodies like the Horticultural Crops Development Authority (HCDA) in Kenya may be merely a promotional body, dealing with advertising, information flows and so on, or it may be active in exporting itself, particularly giving approval (like HCDA does) to all export documents. In direct exporting the major problem is that of market information. The exporter's task is to choose a market, find a representative or agent, set up the physical distribution and documentation, promote and price the product. Control, or the lack of it, is a major problem which often results in decisions on pricing, certification and promotion being in the hands of others. Certainly, the phytosanitary requirements in Europe for horticultural produce sourced in Africa are getting very demanding. Similarly, exporters are price takers as produce is sourced also from the Caribbean and Eastern countries. In the months June to September, Europe is "on season" because it can grow its own produce, so prices are low. As such, producers are better supplying to local food processors. In the European winter prices are much better, but product competition remains.
According to Collett4 (1991)) exporting requires a partnership between exporter, importer, government and transport. Without these four coordinating activities the risk of failure is increased. Contracts between buyer and seller are a must. Forwarders and agents can play a vital role in the logistics procedures such as booking air space and arranging documentation. A typical coordinated marketing channel for the export of Kenyan horticultural produce is given in figure 7.4.
In this case the exporters can also be growers and in the low season both these and other exporters may send produce to food processors which is also exported.
Figure 7.4 The export marketing channel for Kenyan horticultural products.
Exporting can be very lucrative, especially 'if it is of high value added produce. For example in 1992/93 Zimbabwe exported 5 338,38 tonnes of flowers, 4 678,18 tonnes of horticultural produce and 12 000 tonnes of citrus at a total value of about US$ 22 016,56 million. In some cases a mixture of direct and indirect exporting may be achieved with mixed results. For example, the Grain Marketing Board of Zimbabwe may export grain directly to Zambia, or may sell it to a relief agency like the United Nations, for feeding the Mozambican refugees in Malawi. Payment arrangements may be different for the two transactions.
Nali products of Malawi gives an interesting example of a "passive to active" exporting mode.
CASE 7.1 Nali Producers - Malawi
Nali group, has, since the early 1970s, been engaged in the growing and exporting of spices. Spices are also used in the production of a variety of sauces for both the local and export market. Its major success has been the growing and exporting of Birdseye chilies. In the early days knowledge of the market was scanty and thus the company was obtaining ridiculously low prices. Towards the end of 1978 Nali chilies were in great demand, yet still the company, in its passive mode, did not fully appreciate the competitive implications of the business until a number of firms, including Lonrho and Press Farming, started to grow and export.
Again, due to the lack of information, a product of its passivity, the firm did not realise that Uganda, with their superior product, and Papua New Guinea were major exporters, However, the full potential of these countries was hampered by internal difficulties. Nali was able to grow into a successful commercial enterprise. However, with the end of the internal problems, Uganda in particular, began an aggressive exporting policy, using their overseas legations as commercial propagandists. Nali had to respond with a more formal and active marketing operation. However it is being now hampered by a number of important "exogenous" factors.
The entry of a number of new Malawian growers, with inferior products, has damaged the Malawian chili reputation, so has the lack of a clear Government policy and the lack of financing for traders, growers and exporters.
The latter only serves to emphasise the point made by Collett, not only do organisations need to be aggressive, they also need to enlist the support of Government and importers.
It is interesting to note that Korey (1986) warns that direct modes of market entry may be less and less available in the future. Growing trading blocs like the EU or EFTA means that the establishing of subsidiaries may be one of the only means forward in future.
It is interesting to note that Korey5 1986 warned that direct modes of market entry may be less and less available in the future. Growing trading blocks like the EU or EFTA means that the establishment of subsidiaries may be one of the only ways forward in future. Indirect methods of exporting include the use of trading companies (very much used for commodities like cotton, soya, cocoa), export management companies, piggybacking and countertrade.
Indirect methods offer a number of advantages including:
· Contracts - in the operating market or worldwide
· Commission sates give high motivation (not necessarily loyalty)
· Manufacturer/exporter needs little expertise
· Credit acceptance takes burden from manufacturer.
Piggybacking
Piggybacking is an interesting development. The method means that organisations with little exporting skill may use the services of one that has. Another form is the consolidation of orders by a number of companies in order to take advantage of bulk buying. Normally these would be geographically adjacent or able to be served, say, on an air route. The fertilizer manufacturers of Zimbabwe, for example, could piggyback with the South Africans who both import potassium from outside their respective countries.
Countertrade
By far the largest indirect method of exporting is countertrade. Competitive intensity means more and more investment in marketing. In this situation the organisation may expand operations by operating in markets where competition is less intense but currency based exchange is not possible. Also, countries may wish to trade in spite of the degree of competition, but currency again is a problem. Countertrade can also be used to stimulate home industries or where raw materials are in short supply. It can, also, give a basis for reciprocal trade.
Estimates vary, but countertrade accounts for about 20-30% of world trade, involving some 90 nations and between US $100-150 billion in value. The UN defines countertrade as "commercial transactions in which provisions are made, in one of a series of related contracts, for payment by deliveries of goods and/or services in addition to, or in place of, financial settlement".
Countertrade is the modem form of barter, except contracts are not legal and it is not covered by GATT. It can be used to circumvent import quotas.
Countertrade can take many forms. Basically two separate contracts are involved, one for the delivery of and payment for the goods supplied and the other for the purchase of and payment for the goods imported. The performance of one contract is not contingent on the other although the seller is in effect accepting products and services from the importing country in partial or total settlement for his exports. There is a broad agreement that countertrade can take various forms of exchange like barter, counter purchase, switch trading and compensation (buyback). For example, in 1986 Albania began offering items like spring water, tomato juice and chrome ore in exchange for a contract to build a US $60 million fertilizer and methanol complex. Information on potential exchange can be obtained from embassies, trade missions or the EU trading desks.
Barter is the direct exchange of one good for another, although valuation of respective commodities is difficult, so a currency is used to underpin the item's value.
Barter trade can take a number of formats. Simple barter is the least complex and oldest form of bilateral, non-monetarised trade. Often it is called "straight", "classical" or "pure" barter. Barter is a direct exchange of goods and services between two parties. Shadow prices are approximated for products flowing in either direction. Generally no middlemen are involved. Usually contracts for no more than one year are concluded, however, if for longer life spans, provisions are included to handle exchange ratio fluctuations when world prices change.
Closed end barter deals are modifications of straight barter in that a buyer is found for goods taken in barter before the contract is signed by the two trading parties. No money is involved and risks related to product quality are significantly reduced.
Clearing account barter, also termed clearing agreements, clearing arrangements, bilateral clearing accounts or simply bilateral clearing, is where the principle is for the trades to balance without either party having to acquire hard currency. In this form of barter, each party agrees in a single contract to purchase a specified and usually equal value of goods and services. The duration of these transactions is commonly one year, although occasionally they may extend over a longer time period. The contract's value is expressed in non-convertible, clearing account units (also termed clearing dollars) that effectively represent a line of credit in the central bank of the country with no money involved.
Clearing account units are universally accepted for the accounting of trade between countries and parties whose commercial relationships are based on bilateral agreements. The contract sets forth the goods to be exchanged, the rates of exchange, and the length of time for completing the transaction. Limited export or import surpluses may be accumulated by either party for short periods. Generally, after one year's time, imbalances are settled by one of the following approaches: credit against the following year, acceptance of unwanted goods, payment of a previously specified penalty or payment of the difference in hard currency.
Trading specialists have also initiated the practice of buying clearing dollars at a discount for the purpose of using them to purchase saleable products. In turn, the trader may forfeit a portion of the discount to sell these products for hard currency on the international market. Compared with simple barter, clearing accounts offer greater flexibility in the length of time for drawdown on the lines of credit and the types of products exchanged.
Counter purchase, or buyback, is where the customer agrees to buy goods on condition that the seller buys some of the customer's own products in return (compensatory products). Alternatively, if exchange is being organised at national government level then the seller agrees to purchase compensatory goods from an unrelated organisation up to a pre-specified value (offset deal). The difference between the two is that contractual obligations related to counter purchase can extend over a longer period of time and the contract requires each party to the deal to settle most or all of their account with currency or trade credits to an agreed currency value.
Where the seller has no need for the item bought he may sell the produce on, usually at a discounted price, to a third party. This is called a switch deal. In the past a number of tractors have been brought into Zimbabwe from East European countries by switch deals.
Compensation (buy-backs) is where the supplier agrees to take the output of the facility over a specified period of time or to a specified volume as payment. For example, an overseas company may agree to build a plant in Zambia, and output over an agreed period of time or agreed volume of produce is exported to the builder until the period has elapsed. The plant then becomes the property of Zambia.
Khoury6 (1984) categorises countertrade as follows (see figure 7.5):
One problem is the marketability of products received in countertrade. This problem can be reduced by the use of specialised trading companies which, for a fee ranging between 1 and 5% of the value of the transaction, will provide trade related services like transportation, marketing, financing, credit extension, etc. These are ever growing in size.
Countertrade has disadvantages:
· Not covered by GATT so "dumping" may occur· Quality is not of international standard so costly to the customer and trader
· Variety is tow so marketing of wkat is limited
· Difficult to set prices and service quality
· Inconsistency of delivery and specification,
· Difficult to revert to currency trading - so quality may decline further and therefore product is harder to market.
Figure 7.5 Classification of countertrade
Shipley and Neale7 (1988) therefore suggest the following:
· Ensure the benefits outweigh the disadvantages· Try to minimise the ratio of compensation goods to cash - if possible inspect the goods for specifications
· Include all transactions and other costs involved in countertrade in the nominal value specified for the goods being sold
· Avoid the possibility of error of exploitation by first gaining a thorough understanding of the customer's buying systems, regulations and politics,
· Ensure that any compensation goods received as payment are not subject to import controls.
Despite these problems countertrade is likely "to grow as a major indirect entry method, especially in developing countries.
Foreign production
Besides exporting, other market entry strategies include licensing, joint ventures, contract manufacture, ownership and participation in export processing zones or free trade zones.
Licensing: Licensing is defined as "the method of foreign operation whereby a firm in one country agrees to permit a company in another country to use the manufacturing, processing, trademark, know-how or some other skill provided by the licensor".
It is quite similar to the "franchise" operation. Coca Cola is an excellent example of licensing. In Zimbabwe, United Bottlers have the licence to make Coke.
Licensing involves little expense and involvement. The only cost is signing the agreement and policing its implementation.
Licensing gives the following advantages:
· Good way to start in foreign operations and open the door to low risk manufacturing relationships
· Linkage of parent and receiving partner interests means both get most out of marketing effort
· Capital not tied up in foreign operation and
· Options to buy into partner exist or provision to take royalties in stock.
The disadvantages are:
· Limited form of participation - to length of agreement, specific product, process or trademark
· Potential returns from marketing and manufacturing may be lost
· Partner develops know-how and so licence is short
· Licensees become competitors - overcome by having cross technology transfer deals and
· Requires considerable fact finding, planning, investigation and interpretation.
Those who decide to license ought to keep the options open for extending market participation. This can be done through joint ventures with the licensee.
Joint ventures
Joint ventures can be defined as "an enterprise in which two or more investors share ownership and control over property rights and operation".
Joint ventures are a more extensive form of participation than either exporting or licensing. In Zimbabwe, Olivine industries has a joint venture agreement with HJ Heinz in food processing.
Joint ventures give the following advantages:
· Sharing of risk and ability to combine the local in-depth knowledge with a foreign partner with know-how in technology or process· Joint financial strength
· May be only means of entry and
· May be the source of supply for a third country.
They also have disadvantages:
· Partners do not have full control of management
· May be impossible to recover capital if need be
· Disagreement on third party markets to serve and
· Partners may have different views on expected benefits.
If the partners carefully map out in advance what they expect to achieve and how, then many problems can be overcome.
Ownership: The most extensive form of participation is 100% ownership and this involves the greatest commitment in capital and managerial effort. The ability to communicate and control 100% may outweigh any of the disadvantages of joint ventures and licensing. However, as mentioned earlier, repatriation of earnings and capital has to be carefully monitored. The more unstable the environment the less likely is the ownership pathway an option.
These forms of participation: exporting, licensing, joint ventures or ownership, are on a continuum rather than discrete and can take many formats. Anderson and Coughlan8 (1987) summarise the entry mode as a choice between company owned or controlled methods - "integrated" channels - or "independent" channels. Integrated channels offer the advantages of planning and control of resources, flow of information, and faster market penetration, and are a visible sign of commitment. The disadvantages are that they incur many costs (especially marketing), the risks are high, some may be more effective than others (due to culture) and in some cases their credibility amongst locals may be lower than that of controlled independents. Independent channels offer lower performance costs, risks, less capital, high local knowledge and credibility. Disadvantages include less market information flow, greater coordinating and control difficulties and motivational difficulties. In addition they may not be willing to spend money on market development and selection of good intermediaries may be difficult as good ones are usually taken up anyway.
Once in a market, companies have to decide on a strategy for expansion. One may be to concentrate on a few segments in a few countries - typical are cashewnuts from Tanzania and horticultural exports from Zimbabwe and Kenya - or concentrate on one country and diversify into segments. Other activities include country and market segment concentration - typical of Coca Cola or Gerber baby foods, and finally country and segment diversification. Another way of looking at it is by identifying three basic business strategies: stage one - international, stage two - multinational (strategies correspond to ethnocentric and polycentric orientations respectively) and stage three - global strategy (corresponds with geocentric orientation). The basic philosophy behind stage one is extension of programmes and products, behind stage two is decentralisation as far as possible to local operators and behind stage three is an integration which seeks to synthesize inputs from world and regional headquarters and the country organisation. Whilst most developing countries are hardly in stage one, they have within them organisations which are in stage three. This has often led to a "rebellion" against the operations of multinationals, often unfounded.
Export processing zones (EPZ)
Whilst not strictly speaking an entry-strategy, EPZs serve as an "entry" into a market. They are primarily an investment incentive for would be investors but can also provide employment for the host country and the transfer of skills as well as provide a base for the flow of goods in and out of the country. One of the best examples is the Mauritian EPZ12, founded in the 1970s.
CASE 7.2 The Mauritian Export Processing Zone
Since its inception over 400 firms have established themselves in sectors as diverse as textiles, food, watches. And plastics. In job employment the results have been startling, as at 1987, 78,000 were employed in the EPZ. Export earnings have tripled from 1981 to 1986 and the added value has been significant- The roots of success can be seen on the supply, demand and institutional sides. On the supply side the most critical factor has been the generous financial and other incentives, on the demand side, access to the EU, France, India and Hong Kong was very tempting to investors. On the institutional side positive schemes were put in place, including finance from the Development Bank and the cutting of red tape. In setting up the export processing zone the Mauritian government displayed a number of characteristics which in hindsight, were crucial to its success.
· The government intelligently sought a development strategy in an apolitical manner
· It stuck to its strategy in the long run rather than reverse course at the first sign of trouble
· It encouraged market incentives rather than undermined them
· It showed a good deal of adaptability, meeting each challenge with creative solutions rather than maintaining the status quo
· It adjusted the general export promotion programme to suit its own particular needs and characteristics.
· It consciously guarded against the creation of an unwieldy bureaucratic structure.
Organisations are faced with a number of strategy alternatives when deciding to enter foreign markets. Each one has to be carefully weighed in order to make the most appropriate choice. Every approach requires careful attention to marketing, risk, matters of control and management. A systematic assessment of the different entry methods can be achieved through the use of a matrix (see table 7.2).
Table 7.2 Matrix for comparing alternative methods of market entry
Entry mode | ||||||||
Evaluation criteria | Indirect export | Direct export | Marketing subsidiary | Counter trade | Licensing | Joint venture | Wholly owned operation | EPZ |
a) Company goals | ||||||||
b) Size of company | ||||||||
c) Resources | ||||||||
d) Product | ||||||||
e) Remittance | ||||||||
f) Competition | ||||||||
g) Middlemen characteristics | ||||||||
h) Environmental characteristics | ||||||||
i) Number of markets | ||||||||
j) Market | ||||||||
k) Market feedback | ||||||||
l) International market learning | ||||||||
m) Control | ||||||||
n) Marketing costs | ||||||||
o) Profits | ||||||||
p) Investment | ||||||||
q) Administration personnel | ||||||||
r) Foreign problems | ||||||||
s) Flexibility | ||||||||
t) Risk |
Details of channel management will appear in a later chapter.
Special features of commodity trade
As has been pointed out time and again in this text, the international marketing of agricultural products is a "close coupled" affair between production and marketing and end user. Certain characteristics can be identified in market entry strategies which are different from the marketing of say cars or television sets. These refer specifically to the institutional arrangements linking producers and processors/exporters and those between exporters and foreign buyers/agents.
Institutional links between producers and processors/exporters
One of the most important factors is contract coordination. Whilst many of the details vary, most contracts contain the supply of credit/production inputs, specifications regarding quantity, quality and timing of producer deliveries and a formula or price mechanism. Such arrangements have improved the flow of money, information and technologies, and very importantly, shared the risk between producers and exporters.
Most arrangements include some form of vertical integration between producers and downstream activities. Often processors enter into contracted outgrower arrangements or supply raw inputs. This institutional arrangement has now, incidentally, spilled over into the domestic market where firms are wishing to target higher quality, higher priced segments.
Producer trade associations, boards or cooperatives have played a significant part in the entry strategies of many exporting countries. They act as a contact point between suppliers and buyers, obtain vital market information, liaise with Governments over quotas etc. and provide information, or even get involved in quality standards. Some are very active, witness the Horticultural Crops Development Authority (HCDA) of Kenya and the Citrus Marketing Board (CMD) of Israel, the latter being a Government agency which specifically got involved in supply quotas. An example of the institutional arrangements13 involved is given in table 7.3.
Table 7.3 Institutional arrangements linking producers with processors/exporters
Commodity | Market | Contract | Ownership | Association | Government | Marketing risk reduction |
Kenya vegetables | X | X | X | X | ||
Zimbabwe horticulture | X | X | X | X | ||
Israel fresh fruits | ||||||
Thailand tuna | XX | X | X | X | ||
Argentina beef | X | X | X |
XX = Dominant linkage
Institutional links between exporters and foreign buyers/agents
Linkages between exporters and foreign buyers are often dominated by open market trade or spot market sales or sales on consignment. The physical distances involved are also very significant.
Most contracts are of a seasonal, annual or other nature. Some products are handled by multinationals, others by formal integration by processors, building up import/distribution firms. In the case of Kenyan fresh vegetables familial ties are very important between exporters and importers. These linkages have been very important in maintaining market excess, penetrating expanding markets and in obtaining market and product change information, thus reducing considerably the risks of doing business. In some cases, Government gets involved in negotiating deals with foreign countries, either through trade agreements or other mechanisms. Zimbabwe's imports of Namibian mackerel were the result of such a Government negotiated deal. Table 7.413 gives examples of linkages between exporters and foreign buyers/agents.
Table 7.4 Linkages between exporters and foreign buyers/agents.
Commodity | Market | Contract | Ownership interaction | Association | Government | Marketing risk reduction |
Kenya vegetables | X | X | X | X | ||
Zimbabwe horticulture | X | X | X | X | ||
Israel fresh fruits | X | X | X | |||
Thailand tuna | X | XX | XX | X | X | |
Argentina beef | XX | X | XX | X | X | X |
XX = Dominant linkage
Once again, it can not be over-emphasized that the smooth flow between producers, marketers and end users is essential. However it must also be noted that unless strong relationships or contracts are built up and product qualities maintained, the smooth flow can be interrupted should a more competitive supplier enter the market. This also can occur by Government decree, or by the erection of non-tariff barriers to trade. By improving strict hygiene standards a marketing chain can be broken, however strong the link, by say, Government. This, however, should not occur, if the link involves the close monitoring and action by the various players in the system, who are aware, through market intelligence, of any possible changes.
Chapter Summary
Having done all the preparatory planning work (no mean task in itself!), the prospective global marketer has then to decide on a market entry strategy and a marketing mix. These are two main ways of foreign market entryeither by entering from a home market base, via direct or indirect exporting, or by foreign based production. Within these two possibilities, marketers can adopt an "aggressive" or "passive" export path.
Entry from the home base (direct) includes the use of agents, distributors, Government and overseas subsidiaries and (indirect) includes the use of trading companies, export management companies, piggybacking or countertrade. Entry from a foreign base includes licensing, joint ventures, contract manufacture, ownership and export processing zones. Each method has its peculiar advantages and disadvantages which the marketer must carefully consider before making a choice.
Key Terms
Aggressive exporter | Exporting | Licensing |
Barter | Export processing zones | Market entry |
Countertrade | Joint ventures | Passive exporter |
Review Questions
1. Review the general problems encountered when building market entry strategies for agricultural commodities. Give examples.
2. Describe briefly the different methods of foreign market entry.
3. What are the advantages and disadvantages of barter, countertrade, licensing, joint venture and export processing zones as market entry strategies?
Review Question Answers
1. General problems:
i) Interlinking of production and marketing means private investment alone may not be possible, so Government intervention may be needed also e.g. to build infrastructure e.g. Israeli fresh fruit.ii) Licensing
Definition:
Method of foreign operation whereby a firm in one country agrees to permit a company in another country to use the manufacturing, processing, trademark, knowhow or some other skill by the licensor.
ii) "Lumpy investment" building capacity long before it may be currently utilised e.g. port facilities
Advantages:
· entry point with risk reduction,
· benefits to both parties,
· capital not tied up,
· opportunities to buy into partner or royalties on the stock.
iii) Time - processing, transport and storage - so credit is needed e.g. Argentina beef.
iv) Transaction costs - logistics, market information, regulatory enforcement.
Disadvantages:
· limited form or participation,
· potential returns from marketing and manufacturing may be lost,
· partner develops knowhow and so license is short,
· partner becomes competitor,
· requires a lot of planning beforehand.
v) Risk - business, non-business
iv) Joint ventures -
Definition:
An enterprise in which two or more investors share ownership and control over property rights and operation.
vi) Building of relationships and infrastructural developments "correct formats"
2. Different methods
These are either "direct", "indirect" or "foreign" based.
Advantages:
· sharing of risk and knowhow,
· may be only means of entry,
· may be source of supply for third country.
Direct - Agent, distributor, Government, overseas subsidiary
Disadvantages:
· partners do not have full control or management,
· may be impossible to recover capital,
· disagreement between purchasers or third party - served markets,
· partners have different views on exported benefits.
Indirect - Trading company, export management company, piggyback, countertrade
v) Export processing zones -
Definition:
A zone within a country, exempt from tax and duties, for the processing or reprocessing of goods for export
Foreign - Licensing, joint venture, contract manufacture, ownership, export processing zone.
Students should give a definition and expand on each of these methods.
Advantages:
· host country obtains knowhow,
· capital, technology, employment opportunities;
· foreign exchange earnings;
· "reputation", "internationalisation".
3i) Barter-
Definition:
Direct exchange of one good for another. (may be straight or closed or clearing account method)
Disadvantages:
· short term investments,
· capital movements,
· employment movements,
· transaction costs and benefits,
· not part of economy so alienisation,
· labour laws may be different,
· bureaucracy creation.
Advantages:
· simple to administer,
· no currency,
· commodity based valuation or currency based valuation.
Disadvantages:
· risk of non delivery,
· poor quality,
· technological obsolescence,
· unfulfilled quantities,
· risk of commodity price rise thus losing out on an increased valuation,
· depressed valuation,
· marketability of products.
ii) Countertrade -
Definition:
Customer agrees to buy goods on condition that the seller buys some of the customer's own products in return (may be time, method of financing, balance of compensation or pertinence of compensating product based)
Advantages:
· method of obtaining sales by seller and getting a slice of the order,
· method of breaking into a "closed" market.
Disadvantages:
· not covered by GATT,
· so dumping may occur,
· usuality differences, variety differences,
· difficult to set price and service quality,
· inconsistency of delivery and specification,
· difficult to revert to currency trading.
Exercise 7.1 Market entry strategies
Take a major non-traditional crop or agricultural product which your country produces with sales potential overseas. Devise a market entry strategy for the product, clearly showing which you would use and justify your choice indicating why the method chosen would give benefits to your country and the intended importing country(s).
References
1. Cunningham, M.T. "Strategies for International Industrial Marketing". In D.W. Turnbull and J.P. Valla (eds.) Croom Helm 1986, p 9.
2. Pavord and Bogart. "Quoted in The Export Marketing Decision" S.A. Hara in S. Carter (Ed) "Export Procedures", Network and Centre for Agricultural Marketing Training in Eastern and Southern Africa 1991.
3. Piercy, N. "Company Internationalisation: Active and Reactive Exporting". European Journal of Marketing, Vol. 15, No. 3, 1982, pp 26-40.
4. Collett, W.E. "International Transport and Handling of Horticultural Produce" in S. Carter (ed.) "Horticultural Marketing". Network and Centre for Agricultural Marketing Training in Eastern and Southern Africa, 1991.
5. Korey, G. "Multilateral Perspectives in International Marketing Dynamics". European Journal of Marketing, Vol. 20, No. 7, 1986, pp 34-42.
6. Khoury, S.J "Countertrade: Forms, Motives, Pitfalls and Negotiation Requisites". Journal of Business Research, Vol. 12, 1984, pp 257-270.
7. Shipley, D.D. and Neale, C.W. "Successful Countertrading. Management Decision", Vol. 26, No. 1, pp 49-52.
8. Anderson, E. and Coughlan, A.T. "International Market Entry and Expansion via Independent or Integrated Channels of Distribution". Journal of Marketing, Vol. 51. January 1987, pp 71-82.
Bibliography
9. Keegan, W.J. "Global Marketing Management", 4th ed. Prentice Hall International Editions, 1989.
10. Khoromana, A.P. "The Experience and Problems in Exporting Spices". In S. Carter (ed.) Export Procedures Network and Centre for Agricultural Marketing Training in Eastern and Southern Africa, August 1991.
11. Basche, J.R. Jr. "Export Marketing Services and Costs". New York: The Conference Board, 1971, p4.
12. Bheenich, R. and Shapiro, M.O. Mauritius: "A Case Study of the Export Processing Zone. In Successful African Development", EDI Development Policy Case Series, No. 1, 1989, pp 97-127.
13. Jaffee S. "Exporting High Value Food Commodities". "World Bank Discussion Paper" pp 198, 1993.
International Financial Management 6e Chapter 7 Solutions
Source: https://www.fao.org/3/w5973e/w5973e0b.htm